PLANNING DEFINITIONS
Planning refers to the
process of deciding what to do and how to do it. (Littman, Todd. 2013. Planning Principles and
Practices. www.vtpi.org/planning.pdf. page 3)
Planning
as a general activity is the making of an orderly sequence of action that will
lead to the achievement of a stated goal or goals. Its main techniques will be
written statements, supplemented as appropriate by statistical projections, mathematical
representations, quantified evaluations and diagrams illustrating relationships
between different parts of the plan. It may, but need not necessarily, include exact
physical blueprints of objects.(Hall, URP p.3)
Planning is deciding in
advance what is to be done, when, where, how and by whom it is to be done.
Planning bridges the gap
from where we are to where we want to go.
It includes the
selection of objectives, policies, procedures and programmes from among
alternatives (Mantri, et al. ppt. Prestige Institute Of Management &Research ,Indore)
Planning is a decision-making process: an activity that one does now,
the results of which are expected to happen in the future
Planning is the process of choosing alternatives among different courses
of action to attain a certain objective
Planning is problem solving. It is a systematic process of establishing
ends that define direction of future development and determining means and
procedures to achieve the end
Planning is a
deliberate, organized and continuous process of identifying different elements
and aspects of the environment, determining their present state and
interaction, projecting them in concert throughout a period in time in the
future and formulating and programming a set of actions or interventions to
attain desired results.
It pays attention to
the location, form, intensity, and effect of human activities on the built and
un-built environments, anticipating change, and managing such change
sustainably
Source: ENVIRONMENTAL PLANNING
CONCEPTS, THEORIES & PRINCIPLES
Christian “Keesha” R. Buted, 5 March 2017
NINE IMPORTANT
ELEMENTS OF PLANNING
1. Aim/Vision
A plan should have a definite
aim or vision. This is the most ideal desired end state of an organization
which serves as the brightest star that guides the plan, the planners, the
implementers and the community as a whole. For it to be considered a good
vision, it should be reflective of the ultimate desires of the people. It
should be all encompassing and inclusive as to include all sectors and areas of
development.
2. Objectives
This presents the direction as
to where the activities are headed to. As has always been pointed out, it
should be SMART or specific, measurable, attainable, reliable and time-bounded.
3. Policies
This is a written or verbal guide
for actions of the organization. This is being observed in all stages of the
plan as to whether people are doing things properly.
4. Procedures
This is the step by step process
that guides people as they carry on activities and tasks in pursuance of the
objectives. Procedures can be static, however, it should also be flexible
depending on the situation that implementers may face along the way.
5. Methods
This refers to the work plans
which is needed to keep it aligned with the time frame, budget and objectives.
While procedure is broader in scope, method is very specific to a certain area
or department.
6. Rules
This refers to a specific
action and definite action to be taken in a specific situation. This is much
targeted and specific than procedures and policies.
7. Budget
This ensures the implementation
of the plan as this includes the financial requirements or fund allocation needed.
8. Programs
This
lays down the procedures, policies, methods, time frames and resources needed to
carry out the objectives of the plan.
9. Strategies
Koontz and O'Donnell consider
this as an important planning element. "Strategy concerns the direction in
which human and physical resources will be deployed and applied in order to
maximize the chance of achieving a selected objective in the face of
difficulties".
This serves as a master plan
which the company adopts for the realization of the objectives. It provides
skill and judgment to the management to predict and foresee what difficult and
complex situations are likely to arise and they can take timely action to avert
them or at least to minimize the risk and uncertainty.
PRINCIPLES OF PLANNING:
My Personal Reflections
I adhere to the principles of
planning being espoused by no less than John Maxwell as follows:
1.
The
Principle of Passion
I consider planning not as a
job but as a mission. This is what keeps me alive and energizes me every day.
It does not give me a higher pay but the satisfaction of taking an active role
in the development planning process in our municipality and seeing these plans
coming into reality is more precious than any amount of salary. I can only thank
God because out of the thousands of people in this community, He gave me this
rare opportunity of working at the planning office.
Facilitating the planning
process and doing all the documentation are not that easy. With my MPDC, we
have been facing lots of challenges like lacking data, uncooperative members of
the planning team, and admittedly, our lack of technical skills in some
planning areas, like in formulating new plans like Local Climate Change Action
Plan, Peace and Order and Public Safety Plan, Local Shelter Plan and today the
Enhanced CLUP.
With our passion being
translated into sense of urgency and eventually turned into action, we were able
to turn things around notwithstanding challenges and limitations. Today, we
have already had these plans approved by the local sanggunian and now we are in
the half-way of drafting our E-CLUP.
2.
The
Principle of Creativity
Planning is not a one-man
affair. It is a collaborative effort of all the people in the community. Hence,
our development plans are also called people’s plan. To make this possible, a
planning officer should be creative enough to put together representatives of
the people who are development-oriented and technical experts in various
sectors. It is very important to establish a good rapport with them.
A planning officer should also
be creative in convincing the local sanggunian and the local chief executive
about the importance of a certain plan and eventually convince them to allocate
needed budget.
With regards to having a
complete and comprehensive data, a planning officer should be creative enough
to access these data from various offices and individuals.
3.
The
Principle of Influence
In my six-year experience as
planning officer, I have learned that to be a good and effective planner, one
has to have a high level of influence over the local chief executive and the
local sanggunian. In my case, I maintained a good working relationship with my
immediate boss-my MPDC, with the mayor as well as with the members of the
Sangguniang Bayan. This is very important because these people hold the key to
having a successful development planning process. A good name for oneself,
personal integrity and a certain level of competence are where influence is
founded. For me, influence and competence should go together.
4.
The
Principle of Priorities
In my first ten years in the
local government unit, I have been doing multi-tasking. Aside from my regular
job, I have juggled three or more designations like being the tourism officer,
solid waste management officer, and culture and arts coordinator. Such
situation is very common in the LGUs especially here in the province due to
lack of personnel. At first, I enjoyed doing all these things. However, in the
long run, I felt I am already doing a disservice to the community because I can
only do so much. Having three or more designations definitely result to
haphazard performance to the detriment of quality work. I woke up one day I have
so many backlogs already. And this made me unhappy. So, I look for a way to put
a stop to this by looking for other appropriate people who can do these jobs
with the required focus. So, I was able to find other more capable co-employees
in the LGU. I asked the mayor to transfer some of my responsibilities to these
people. Today, I only have planning in my hand and secretariat work for the
mayor. But then, I still help in tourism, culture and arts as well as solid
waste management program in my capacity as planning officer. It is also because
these are also my personal advocacies.
Today, I am now more settled
with my position and more focused on the work that I do at the planning office.
5.
The
Principle of Flexibility
Keeping things in order and
balance is very important in planning. I have been through a number of planning sessions where
facing conflicting interest is very common. There are a number of times when
data being presented by a resource person does not reflect reality. There are
also times when there arise some conflicts or overlaps between environmental
and economic sectors and so with other sectors. When planning already reaches
the stage of identification and prioritization of projects, clashes of biases
happens. These things are just normal. As a planner, I tried to be flexible as
I can without imposing my personal biases. I listen a lot to arguments of both
sides and try to appreciate it all and make sense and connections to their
points. The general welfare and the legal provisions have always been my
guideposts in handling such situations. Of course, in the end the local chief
executive has the final say.
6.
The
Principle of Timing
It pays to be at the right
place and at the right time. One thing I have learned in this job is to know
what to and when to talk and when to keep silent. Being a part of the technical
staff working at the same time with the decision-makers who are actually
politicians needs a lot of balancing act. At the end of the day, I have to keep
myself grounded to the demands of my job and to keep away from taking part in
political bickerings. During planning sessions, saying the right things properly
is very much important.
7.
The
Principle of Teamwork
A plan is only as good as the
team who works for it. Though it is very difficult to muster a hundred percent
cooperation of all, I can say that we have been able to get the right people
for the planning team and generally they are very cooperative. Identifying the
right people for the planning team is very crucial in having a comprehensive
planning sessions and in coming up with a quality plan. Having a good
relationship with them that is founded on mutual respect holds the key in
ensuring teamwork that bear more positive results.
Four Types of Planning
1) Passive planning happens when leadership allows the raft to travel
downstream at the mercy of the current rather than steering, rowing, and
turning. This kind of non-planning eventually leaves you unprepared to face
whitewater rapids. Worse yet, in the absence of a plan, the current may take
the raft over the edge of a dreaded waterfall.
2) Panic planning happens only after the raft is in trouble. At
this point, all of the organization's resources are scrambled in a reactionary
pattern in an attempt to solve the problem. With panic planning, you may or may
not come out alive and well, but you are guaranteed some bumps and bruises.
3)
Scientific planning is
viable, but can be laborious, mechanical, and often ends up abandoned in the
process. Imagine if a raft guide constantly tried to measure the depth of the
water, the distance between rocks, the wind speed, and the water current.
Although the information might be helpful, oftentimes the water would be moving
too swiftly to take the measurements. In a like manner, leaders often have to
respond to change in an instant. There's no time to collect scientific data on
all of the variables before deciding which course of action is best.
4)
Principle-centered planning is the
key to effectiveness. It is the artistic or leadership approach.
Principle-centered planning recognizes that life in general (and people in
particular) can't be graphed on a chart, but sees that planning still remains
essential.
(Maxwell, John C. Seven Principles of
Planning. www.teamexpansion.org/brigguy/articles/Seven_Principles_of_Planning.pdf., page 1)
ADVANTAGES AND
LIMITATIONS OF PLANNING
Advantages of Planning:
Planning is one of the crucial functions of management. It is
basic to all other functions of management. There will not be proper
organization and direction without proper planning. It states the goals and means
of achieving them.
Above all other things,
planning is important for the following reasons:
1. Attention on
Objectives:
Planning helps in clearly laying down objectives of the
organization. The whole attention of management is given towards the achievement
of those objectives. There can be priorities in objectives, important
objectives to be taken up first and others to be followed after them.
2. Minimizing
Uncertainties:
Planning is always done for the future. Nobody can predict
accurately what is going to happen. Business environments are always changing.
Planning is an effort to foresee the future and plan the things in a best
possible way. Planning certainly minimizes future uncertainties by basing its
decisions on past experiences and present situations.
3. Better Utilization of
Resources:
Another advantage of planning is the better utilization of
resources of the business. All the resources are first identified and then
operations are planned. All resources are put to best possible uses.
4. Economy in Operations:
The objectives are determined first and then best possible
course of action is selected for achieving these objectives. The operations
selected being better among possible alternatives, there is an economy in
operations. The method of trial and error is avoided and resources are not
wasted in making choices. The economy is possible in all departments whether
production, sales, purchases, finances, etc.
5. Better Co-ordination:
The objectives of the organization being common, all efforts are
made to achieve these objectives by a concerted effort of all. The duplication
in efforts is avoided. Planning will lead to better co-ordination in the
organization which will ultimately lead to better results.
6. Encourages Innovations
and Creativity:
A better planning system should encourage managers to devise new
ways of doing the things. It helps innovative and creative thinking among
managers because they will think of many new things while planning. It is a
process which will provide awareness for individual participation and will
encourage an atmosphere of frankness which will help in achieving better
results.
7. Management by Exception
Possible:
Management by exception means that management should not be
involved in each and every activity. If the things are going well then there
should be nothing to worry and management should intervene only when things are
not going as per planning. Planning fixes objectives of the organization and
all efforts should be made to achieve these objectives. Management should
interfere only when things are not going well. By the introduction of
management by exception, managers are given more time for planning the
activities rather than wasting their time in directing day-to-day work.
8. Facilitates Control:
Planning and control are inseparable. Planning helps in setting
objectives and laying down performance standards. This will enable the
management to cheek performance of subordinates. The deviations in performance
can be rectified at the earliest by taking remedial measures.
9. Facilitates Delegation:
Under planning process, delegation of powers is facilitated. The
goals of different persons are fixed. They will be requiring requisite
authority for getting the things clone. Delegation of authority is facilitated
through planning process.
LIMITATIONS OF PLANNING:
Despite of many advantages of planning, there may be some
obstacles and limitations in this process. Planning is not a panacea for all
the ills of the business. Planning will only help in minimizing uncertainties
to a certain extent.
The following are some of the
limitations of planning:
1. Lack of Reliable Data:
Planning is based on various facts and figures supplied to the
planners. If the data on which decisions are based are not reliable then
decisions based on such information will also be unreliable. Planning will lose
its value if reliable facts and figures are not supplied.
2. Time Consuming Process:
Practical utility of planning is sometimes reduced by the time
factor. Planning is a time- consuming process and actions on various operations
may be delayed because proper planning has not yet been done. The delay may
result in loss of opportunities. When time is of essence then advance planning
loses its utility. Under certain circumstances an urgent action is needed then
one cannot wait for the planning process to complete.
3. Expensive:
The planning process is very expensive. The gathering of
information and testing of various courses of action involve greater amounts of
money. Sometimes, expenses are so prohibitive that small concerns cannot afford
to use planning. The long-term planning is a luxury for most of the concerns
because of heavy expenses. The utility derived from planning in no case should
be less than expenditure incurred on it.
According to Hainman, “The cost of planning should not be in
excess of its contribution, and wise managerial judgment is necessary to
balance the expense of preparing the plans against the benefits derived from
them.”
4. External Factors may
Reduce Utility:
Besides internal factors there are external factors too which
adversely affect planning. These factors may be economic, social, political,
technological or legal. The general national and international climate also
acts as limitation on the planning process.
5. Sudden Emergencies:
In case certain emergencies arise then the need of the hour is
quick action and not advances planning. These situations may not be
anticipated. In case emergencies are anticipated or they have regularity in
occurrence then advance planning should be undertaken for emergencies too.
6. Resistance to Change:
Most of the persons, generally, do not like any change. Their
passive outlook to new ideas becomes a limitation to planning. McFarland
writes. “The principal psychological barrier is that executives, like most
people have more regard for the present than for the future. The present is not
only more certain than the future, it is also more desirable. Resistance to
change is commonly experienced phenomenon in the business world. Planning often
implies changes which the executive would like to ignore, hoping they would not
materialize.” The notion that things planned for future are unlikely to happen
is not based on logical thinking. It is the planning which helps in minimizing
future uncertainties.
THE LEGAL BASIS OF PLANNING
IN THE PHILIPPINES
A. The 1987 Philippine Constitution provides the basis for
all development efforts. The provisions about planning are specifically found
in Article II, Declaration of Principles and State Policies where the
preparation of the national development plan is mandated.
Among the planning
directions implied in the general principles of the 1987 Constitution are as
follows: Promotion of social justice in all phases of national development
(Sec. 10); Recognition of the vital role of the youth in nation-building,
encouraging their involvement in public and civic affairs (Sec. 13); Recognition of the role of women in
nation-building (Sec. 14); Promotion of
the right to health of the people (Sec. 15);
Advancing the right of the people to a balanced and healthful ecology
(Sec. 16); Promotion of comprehensive rural development and agrarian reform
(Sec. 21); Recognition of the rights of indigenous cultural communities within
the framework of national unity and development (Sec. 22); Involvement of
non-governmental organizations, community- based or sectoral organizations in
public affairs (Sec. 23)
B. The Local Government Code of 1991 (RA 7160) provide the following
provisions for planning:
Section 106 mandates that
each local government unit (LGU) shall have a comprehensive multi-sectoral
development plan to be initiated by its development council and approved by its
Sanggunian.
Section 20 requires that
the local government units shall, in conformity with existing laws, continue to
prepare their respective comprehensive land use plans enacted through zoning
ordinances which shall be the primary and dominant basis for the future use of
land resources.
Section 44 number 1(ii) –
in this provision, the Municipal Mayor is mandated to direct the formulation of
the Municipal Development Plan, with the assistance of the Municipal
Development Council, and upon the approval thereof by the Sangguniang Bayan,
implement the same.
Section 468 paragraph 2
(vii) – this provision mandates the Sangguniang Panlalawigan to review the
Comprehensive Land Use Plans (CLUPs) and zoning ordinances of component cities
and municipalities and adopt a Comprehensive Provincial Land Use Plan (CPLUP),
subject to existing laws.
- Office of the President Memorandum
Circular No. 2:
In this circular dated July 17, 1992, all government departments, offices
and instrumentalities, including the local government units, are directed
to formulate their respective medium-term plans and public investment
programs for the period 1993-1998.
Malacanang Executive
Order No. 72: This issuance dated March 25, 1993 mandated the City or Municipal
Development Council (CDC/MDC) to initiate the formulation or updating of its
land use plan, in consultation with the sectors in the community.
- DILG Memorandum Circular No. 92-41: This circular dated July 6, 1992 mandated the local government units to prepare, as a minimum requirement, their one year of annual investment programs.
COMPONENTS OF LOCAL PLANNING STRUCTURE
Technical and political.
The political component comprises mainly the Local Sanggunian and the LDC. These two bodies
lay down policy guidelines and take decisions regarding the direction,
character, and objectives of local development. They do these in their capacity
as elected representatives of the people. In a very real sense, they are the
true planners of the city, municipality or province. The technical component on the
other hand consists of non-elective officials of the LGU, heads of national
agencies operating in the area, and non-government sectors. (RPS p. 2)
Source: Rationalizing Planning System, DILG, 2008
IMPORTANT NOTES FROM PETER HALL'S
URBAN AND REGIONAL PLANNING BOOK
Against this background the planner
develops an information system which is continuously updated as the region
develops and changes. It will be used to produce various alternative projections,
or simulations, of the state of the region at various future dates, assuming the
application of various policies. (The aim is always to make this process as
flexible and as varied as possible, so that it is possible to look at all sorts
of ways of allowing the region to grow and change.) Then the alternatives are
compared or evaluated against yardsticks derived from the goals and objectives,
to produce a recommended system of policy controls which in turn will be
modified as the objectives are re-examined and as the information system
produces evidence of new developments. Though it is difficult to put this new
sequence into a string of words like the older one, it might be succinctly described
as goals–continuous information–projection and simulation of alternative futures–evaluation–choice–continuous
monitoring. Something like this sequence, with some differences in words and in
ordering, can be found in several important and well known accounts of the
planning process written in the 1960s and early 1970s. (Hall, p.6)
a. Survey-plan-analysis (Geddes)
Information systems are now used very widely
in the planning process. And, as we shall see in later chapters of this book,
it has profoundly affected the way planners think about their job and the way
they produce plans. In essence it has led to a swing from the old idea of
planning as production of blueprints for the future desired state of the area,
and towards the new idea of planning as a continuous series of controls over
the development of the area, aided by devices which seek to model or simulate
the process of development so that this control can be applied. This in turn
has led to a complete change in the sequence of planners’ work. Formerly, at
any time from about 1920 until 1960, the classic sequence taught to all
planning students was survey–analysis–plan. (The notion of survey before plan
had first been worked out, and taught, by a remarkable British pioneer in
planning, Patrick Geddes; his work is discussed in more detail in Chapter 3.)
The terms were self-explanatory. First the planner made a survey, in which s/he
collected all the relevant information about the development of the city or
region. Then s/he analysed the data, seeking to project them as far as possible
into the future to discover how the area was changing and developing. And
third, s/he planned: that is, s/he made a plan which took into account the
facts and interpretations revealed in the survey and analysis, and which sought
to harness and control the trends according to principles of sound planning.
After a few years – the British Planning Act of 1947 laid down that the period
should be every five years – the process should be repeated: the survey should
be carried out again to check for new facts and developments, the analysis should
be reworked to see how far the projections needed modifying, and the plan should
be updated accordingly. (Hall, p6)
b. Cybernetics
The new planning sequence, which has
replaced this older one as orthodoxy, reflects the approach of cybernated
planning. It is more difficult to represent in words because it is a continuous cycle; more
commonly, it is represented as a flow diagram. But, to break into the flow for
purposes of exposition, it can be said to start with the formulation of goals
and objectives for the development of the area concerned. (These should be
continuously refined and redefined during the cycles of the planning process.)
To
sum up: urban and regional planning is spatial or physical: it uses the general
methods of planning to produce a physical design. Because of the increasing
influence of these general methods, it is oriented towards process rather than
towards the production of one-shot (or end-state) plans. Its subject matter is
really that part of geography which is concerned with urban and regional
systems; but the planning itself is a type of management for very complex
systems. And further, it is necessarily multidimensional and multi-objective in
its scope; this is what distinguishes it from the work of many other professionals
whose work can fairly be described as planning with a spatial component. (Hall,
9)
Planning Skills and
Competencies,
Attitude and Behavior, and Kinds of Knowledge
Needed by Planners
Planning Skills
Planners
should strive to truly understand problems, not just a single perspective or
manifestation.
Planners
should strive to understand factors that will affect the future.
Planners
must manage information flows, including gathering, organizing and distribution
(Litman, 2006).
Planners
should anticipate questions and provide accurate and understandable
information, using visual information (maps, graphs, tables, etc.) and
appropriate examples.
Planners
must frequently shift between general concepts and specific applications.
Accurately, critically and objectively
evaluate problems.
Collect and analyze data.
Apply general concepts to specific
situations.
Manage complex processes.
Communicate complex issues with many
types of people.
Listen respectfully.
Planners
manage resources, such as people, time, money, land, and infrastructure.
Planners are professional worriers who seek out potential
problems so they can be mitigated.
Planners are responsible for considering multiple
perspectives; they ask “what is best for everybody overall?”
Planners learn to appreciate complexity, and search for deeper
meanings and underlying causes. Planners learn to work with
uncertainty and ambiguity.
Planners are passionate about compromise because it resolves
conflicts and often leads to better solutions.
Planners apply integrated analysis, so individual,
short-term decisions are consistent with multiple, long-term goals.
(Littman,
Todd. 2013. Planning
Principles and Practices. www.vtpi.org/planning.pdf.
page 3-6)
Attitude and Behavior
|
Objective
and fair.
Prepared
to work with people from diverse backgrounds, interests and abilities.
Diplomatic skills
Good sense of judgment, sensitive and creative
(Littman, Todd. 2013. Planning Principles and Practices. www.vtpi.org/planning.pdf.
pages 3-6)
KNOWLEDGE
Basic
knowledge of many subjects including design, economics, law and management,
making it an ideal field for people with diverse interests.
Knowledge
on new issues and practices – becoming the local expert on a new planning issue.
(Littman, Todd. 2013. Planning Principles and
Practices. www.vtpi.org/planning.pdf.
pages 3-6)
Planners
should have knowledge about…
THEORY
Substantive
- Understanding of law, legal
institutions, codes, ordinances etc.
- Ability to read a zoning code
and interpret its case-related application
- Understanding basic microeconomic theory and
its application
- Understanding of space, issues
concerning the built environment
- Understanding of physical
planning alternatives, what others have tried [also relates to design skills]
- Knowledge of the evolution of
urban forms . . . result(in from) economic, political, social force
- Understanding . . . urban
structure, space dynamics of a City
Familiarity with laws, ordinances, policies . . institutional structures for implementation
- Familiarity with the development
process [also procedural theory]
- Understanding . . .
contemporary urban issues . . . alternative strategies for addressing them
Procedural (Knowledge/understanding
of the planning process)
- Understanding
and articulating “the rationale for planning”
- Familiarity
with the interaction of planning, implementation and markets
- Understanding
of the planning process (who’s involved and timing and dynamics of involvement)
Writing
- Clear,
concise in-house memo writing
- Ability
to write findings, draft ordinances, etc.
- Ability
to write reports, lengthier documents
- Ability
to write . . . short pieces (e.g. brochures etc.) for the
- general
public
Oral Communication/Presentation
- Speaking
formally and informally with public and elected officials
- Graphic Communication/
Presentation
- Ability
to communicate graphically
Analysis and Methods
- Clear,
linear thinking
- Ability
to conduct primary data collection
- Ability
to perform qualitative and quantitative reasoning
- Comfort
and willingness to work with numbers
- Competency
in basic computer programs
- Competency
in GISCompetency in multilinear regression
- Ability
to use land records and blueprints
- Knowledge
of the (uses and limitations) of models and
- forecasts
- Competency
in site analysis
Synthesis, Creativity, and Design
- Ability
to synthesize and reduce four pages into one paragraph
- Ability
to follow a “thin thread” to collect data and information
- (creatively)
from diverse sources
- Ability
to see multiple perspectives and reconcile into a single
- product
- Ability
to access and synthesize secondary data
- Ability
to conceptualize plans in three dimensions [also
- relates
to design skills]
- Competency
with scenario techniques [also analysis]
Management and Coordination
- Coordinating
a multidisciplinary team
- Ability
to develop and maintain budgets
Source: Alexander, E. R. (2001). What do planners
need to know?. Journal of Planning Education and Research, 20(3),
376-380.
GOALS OF PLANNING
The planning goals
focus on the 5Es - Efficiency, Effectiveness, Ecology, Equity and Empowerment
of People.
Each of the planning goals can be achieved through generic strategies. For instance, efficiency can be achieved through engineering and entrepreneurial innovation with the former emphasizing the importance of technology infusions to generate more outputs per unit of input and the latter underscores the need of employing skills in expanding enterprises and venturing to wide array of economic activities. Effectiveness dwells on the enforcement of policies. Ecology addresses the attainment of equilibrium and balance with due consideration on sustainable development. Equity calls for evenhandedness giving the poor and the rich equal access to natural and human resources. Empowerment can be addressed through education and active participation of the different sectors in the planning process. All of these goals are geared towards the improvement of the general well-being of individuals and the society.
Each of the planning goals can be achieved through generic strategies. For instance, efficiency can be achieved through engineering and entrepreneurial innovation with the former emphasizing the importance of technology infusions to generate more outputs per unit of input and the latter underscores the need of employing skills in expanding enterprises and venturing to wide array of economic activities. Effectiveness dwells on the enforcement of policies. Ecology addresses the attainment of equilibrium and balance with due consideration on sustainable development. Equity calls for evenhandedness giving the poor and the rich equal access to natural and human resources. Empowerment can be addressed through education and active participation of the different sectors in the planning process. All of these goals are geared towards the improvement of the general well-being of individuals and the society.
Source: Professor Dina Magnaye
PLANNER'S POINTS OF INTERSECTIONS AND CONFLICTS
Below are the points of intersections and sources
of conflicts of the three points of planner’s triangle which includes economic,
social and environmental. These areas are where planners find themselves in a
situation where balancing act is very much crucial.
Table 1 Sustainability Issues (“Sustainable
Transportation,” VTPI, 2006)
Economic
|
Social
|
Environmental
|
Affordability
Resource
efficiency
Cost
internalization
Employment
and business activity
Productivity
Tax
burden
|
Equity
Human
health
Education
Community
Quality
of life
Public
Participation
|
Pollution
prevention
Climate
protection
Biodiversity
Precautionary
action
Habitat
preservation
Aesthetics
|
Planner’s priorities and conflicts rest on issues
within the framework of economic, environmental and social. Economy versus
environment is common. This is so because in developing the economy, there is
tendency to exploit resources to the detriment of the environment. On the
social aspect, people especially those in the local level are also in need of
jobs and other forms of opportunities. A productive interaction with proponents
for both the development and utilization of these resources is needed. As a
planner, it is wise to look not so much on conflict but on areas of
collaboration so as to balance the interest of those belonging to each sector.
In the first, these areas are not stand-on. Collaboration is the key in order
to avoid conflict. Sustainable development is the way to balance conflicting
interest. Through this, there is a balance in economic development, protection
and preservation of environment and the increasing needs of the people.
The
Planner's Triangle: Three Priorities, Three Conflicts
The
current environmental enthusiasm among planners and planning schools might
suggest their innate predisposition to protect the natural environment.
Unfortunately, the opposite is more likely true: our historic tendency has been
to promote the development of cities at the cost of natural destruction: to
build cities we have cleared forests, fouled rivers and the air, leveled
mountains. That is not the complete picture, since planners also have often
come to the defense of nature, through the work of conservationists, park
planners, open space preservationists, the Regional Planning Association of
America, greenbelt planners, and modern environmental planners. Yet along the
economic-ecological spectrum, with Robert Moses and Dave Foreman (of Earth
First!) standing at either pole, the planner has no natural home, but can
slide from one end to the other; moreover, the midpoint has no special claims
to legitimacy or fairness.
Similarly, though planners often see themselves as the defenders
of the poor and of socio-economic equality, their actions over the profession's
history have often belied that self-image (Harvey 1985). Planners' efforts with
downtown redevelopment, freeway planning, public-private partnerships,
enterprise zones, smokestack-chasing and other economic development strategies
don't easily add up to equity planning. At best, the planner has taken an
ambivalent stance between the goals of economic growth and economic justice.
In short, the planner must reconcile not two, but at least three
conflicting interests: to "grow" the economy, distribute this growth
fairly, and in the process not degrade the ecosystem. To classify contemporary
battles over environmental racism, pollution-producing jobs, growth control,
etc., as simply clashes between economic growth and environmental protection
misses the third issue, of social justice. The "jobs versus environment"
dichotomy (e.g., the spotted owl versus Pacific Northwest timber jobs) crudely
collapses under the "economy" banner the often differing interests of
workers, corporations, community members, and the national public. The intent
of this paper's title is to focus planning not only for "green cities and
growing cities," but also for "just cities."
In an ideal world, planners would strive to achieve a balance of
all three goals. In practice, however, professional and fiscal constraints
drastically limit the leeway of most planners. Serving the broader public
interest by holistically harmonizing growth, preservation, and equality remains
the ideal; the reality of practice restricts planners to serving the narrower
interests of their clients, authorities and bureaucracies (Marcuse 1976),
despite efforts to work outside those limitations (Hoffman 1989). In the end,
planners usually represent one particular goal -- planning perhaps for
increased property tax revenues, or more open space preservation, or better
housing for the poor -- while neglecting the other two. Where each planner
stands in the triangle depicted in figure 1 defines such professional bias. One
may see illustrated in the figure the gap between the call for integrative,
sustainable development planning (the center of the triangle) and the current
fragmentation of professional practice (the edges). This point is developed
later.
Figure 1. The
triangle of conflicting goals for planning, and the three associated conflicts.
Planners define themselves, implicitly, by where they stand on the triangle.
The elusive ideal of sustainable development leads one to the center.
The Points (Corners) of the
Triangle: the Economy, the Environment, and Equity
The
three types of priorities lead to three perspectives on the city: The economic
development planner sees the city as a location where production, consumption,
distribution, and innovation take place. The city is in competition with other
cities for markets and for new industries. Space is the economic space of
highways, market areas, and commuter zones.
The environmental
planner sees the city as a consumer of resources and a producer of wastes. The
city is in competition with nature for scarce resources and land, and always
poses a threat to nature. Space is the ecological space of greenways, river
basins, ecological niches.
The equity planner sees
the city as a location of conflict over the distribution of resources, of
services, and of opportunities. The competition is within the city itself, among
different social groups. Space is the social space of communities, neighborhood
organizations, labor unions: the space of access and segregation.
Certainly there are
other important views of the city, including the architectural, the
psychological, and the circulatory (transportation); and one could conceivably
construct a planner's rectangle, pentagon, or more complex polygons. The
triangular shape itself is not propounded here as the underlying geometric
structure of the planner's world. Rather, it is useful for its conceptual
simplicity. More importantly, it emphasizes the point that a one-dimensional
"man versus environment" spectrum misses the social conflicts in
contemporary environmental disputes, such as loggers versus the Sierra Club,
farmers versus suburban developers, or fishermen versus barge operators
(Reisner 1987; Jacobs 1989; McPhee 1989; Tuason 1993).
Triangle Axis 1: The Property Conflict
The
three points on the triangle represent divergent interests, and therefore lead
to three fundamental conflicts. The first conflict -- between economic growth
and equity -- arises from competing claims on and uses of property, such as
between management and labor, landlords and tenants, or gentrifying
professionals and long-time residents. This growth-equity conflict is further
complicated because each side not only resists the other, but also needs the
other for its own survival. The contradictory tendency for a capitalist,
democratic society to define property (such as housing or land) as a private
commodity, but at the same time to rely on government intervention (e.g.,
zoning, or public housing for the working class) to ensure the beneficial
social aspects of the same property, is what Richard Foglesong (1986) calls the
"property contradiction." This tension is generated as the private
sector simultaneously resists and needs social intervention, given the
intrinsically contradictory nature of property. Indeed, the essence of property
in our society is the tense pulling between these two forces. The conflict
defines the boundary between private interest and the public good.
Triangle Axis 2: The Resource Conflict
Just as
the private sector both resists regulation of property, yet needs it to keep
the economy flowing, so too is society in conflict about its priorities for
natural resources. Business resists the regulation of its exploitation of
nature, but at the same time needs regulation to conserve those resources for
present and future demands. This can be called the "resource conflict."
The conceptual essence of natural resources is therefore the tension between
their economic utility in industrial society and their ecological utility in
the natural environment. This conflict defines the boundary between the
developed city and the undeveloped wilderness, which is symbolized by the
"city limits." The boundary is not fixed; it is a dynamic and
contested boundary between mutually dependent forces.
Is there a single,
universal economic-ecological conflict underlying all such disputes faced by planners?
I searched for this essential, Platonic notion, but the diversity of examples
-- water politics in California, timber versus the spotted owl in the Pacific
Northwest, tropical deforestation in Brazil, park planning in the Adirondacks,
greenbelt planning in Britain, to name a few -- suggests otherwise. Perhaps
there is an Ur-Konflikt, rooted in the fundamental struggle between
human civilization and the threatening wilderness around us, and expressed
variously over the centuries. However, the decision must be left to
anthropologists as to whether the essence of the spotted owl controversy can be
traced back to Neolithic times. A meta-theory tying all these multifarious
conflicts to an essential battle of "human versus nature" (and, once
tools and weapons were developed and nature was controlled, "human versus
human") -- that invites skepticism. In this discussion, the triangle is
used simply as a template to recognize and organize the common themes; to
examine actual conflicts, individual case studies are used.
The economic-ecological
conflict has several instructive parallels with the growth-equity conflict. In
the property conflict, industrialists must curb their profit-increasing
tendency to reduce wages, so as to provide labor enough wages to feed, house,
and otherwise "reproduce" itself -- that is, the subsistence wage. In
the resource conflict, the industrialists must curb their profit-increasing
tendency to increase timber yields, so as to ensure that enough of the forest
remains to "reproduce" itself (Clawson 1975; Beltzer and Kroll 1986;
Lee, Field, and Burch 1990). This practice is called "sustained
yield," though timber companies and environmentalists disagree about how
far the forest can be exploited and still be "sustainable." (Of
course, other factors also affect wages, such as supply and demand, skill
level, and discrimination, just as lumber demand, labor prices, transportation
costs, tariffs, and other factors affect how much timber is harvested.) In both
cases, industry must leave enough of the exploited resource, be it labor or
nature, so that the resource will continue to deliver in the future. In both
cases, how much is "enough" is also contested.
Triangle Axis 3: The Development Conflict
The
third axis on the triangle is the most elusive: the "development
conflict," lying between the poles of social equity and environmental
preservation. If the property conflict is characterized by the economy's
ambivalent interest in providing at least a subsistence existence for working
people, and the resource conflict by the economy's ambivalent interest in
providing sustainable conditions for the natural environment, the development
conflict stems from the difficulty of doing both at once. Environment-equity
disputes are coming to the fore to join the older dispute about economic growth
versus equity (Paehlke 1994, 349-50). This may be the most challenging
conundrum of sustainable development: how to increase social equity and protect
the environment simultaneously, whether in a steady-state economy (Daly 1991)
or not. How could those at the bottom of society find greater economic
opportunity if environmental protection mandates diminished economic growth? On
a global scale, efforts to protect the environment might lead to slowed
economic growth in many countries, exacerbating the inequalities between rich
and poor nations. In effect, the developed nations would be asking the poorer
nations to forgo rapid development to save the world from the greenhouse effect
and other global emergencies.
This development
conflict also happens at the local level, as in resource-dependent communities,
which commonly find themselves at the bottom of the economy's hierarchy of
labor. Miners, lumberjacks, and mill workers see a grim link between
environmental preservation and poverty, and commonly mistrust environmentalists
as elitists. Poor urban communities are often forced to make the no-win choice
between economic survival and environmental quality, as when the only economic
opportunities are offered by incinerators, toxic waste sites, landfills, and
other noxious land uses that most neighborhoods can afford to oppose and do
without (Bryant and Mohai 1992; Bullard 1990, 1993). If some argue that
environmental protection is a luxury of the wealthy, then environmental racism
lies at the heart of the development conflict. Economic segregation leads to
environmental segregation: the former occurs in the transformation of natural
resources into consumer products; the latter occurs as the spoils of production
are returned to nature. Inequitable development takes place at all stages of
the materials cycle.
Consider this conflict
from the vantage of equity planning. Norman Krumholz, as the planning director
in Cleveland, faced the choice of either building regional rail lines or
improving local bus lines (Krumholz et al. 1982). Regional rail lines would
encourage the suburban middle class to switch from cars to mass transit; better
local bus service would help the inner-city poor by reducing their travel and
waiting time. One implication of this choice was the tension between reducing
pollution and making transportation access more equitable, an example of how
bias toward social inequity may be embedded in seemingly objective transit
proposals.
Implications
of the Planner's Triangle Model
Conflict and Complementarity in the Triangle
Though
I use the image of the triangle to emphasize the strong conflicts among
economic growth, environmental protection, and social justice, no point can
exist alone. The nature of the three axial conflicts is mutual dependence based
not only on opposition, but also on collaboration.
Consider the argument
that the best way to distribute wealth more fairly (i.e., to resolve the
property conflict) is to increase the size of the economy, so that society will
have more to redistribute. Similarly, we can argue that the best way to improve
environmental quality (i.e., to resolve the resource conflict) is to expand the
economy, thereby having more money with which to buy environmental protection.
The former is trickle-down economics; can we call the latter "trickle-down
environmentalism"? One sees this logic in the conclusion of the Brundtland
Report: "If large parts of the developing world are to avert economic,
social, and environmental catastrophes, it is essential that global economic
growth be revitalized." (World Commission on Environment and Development
1987). However, only if such economic growth is more fairly distributed will
the poor be able to restore and protect their environment, whose devastation so
immediately degrades their quality of life. In other words, the development
conflict can be resolved only if the property conflict is resolved as well.
Therefore, the challenge for planners is to deal with the conflicts between
competing interests by discovering and implementing complementary uses.
The Triangle's Origins in a Social View of
Nature
One of
the more fruitful aspects of recent interdisciplinary thought may be its
linking the traditionally separate intellectual traditions of critical social
theory and environmental science/policy (e.g., Smith 1990; Wilson, 1992; Ross
1994). This is also the purpose of the triangle figure presented here: to
integrate the environmentalist's and social theorist's world views. On one side,
an essentialist view of environmental conflicts ("man versus nature")
emphasizes the resource conflict. On another side, a historical materialist
view of social conflicts (e.g., capital versus labor) emphasizes the property
conflict. By simultaneously considering both perspectives, one can see more
clearly the social dimension of environmental conflicts, that is, the
development conflict. Such a synthesis is not easy: it requires accepting the
social construction of nature but avoiding the materialistic pitfall of
arrogantly denying any aspects of nature beyond the labor theory of value.
Environmental conflict
should not, therefore, be seen as simply one group representing the interests
of nature and another group attacking nature (though it often appears that
way). Who is to say that the lumberjack, who spends all his or her days among
trees (and whose livelihood depends on those trees), is any less close to
nature than the environmentalist taking a weekend walk through the woods? Is
the lumberjack able to cut down trees only because s/he is
"alienated" from the "true" spirit of nature -- the spirit
that the hiker enjoys? In the absence of a forest mythology, neither the tree
cutter nor the tree hugger -- nor the third party, the owner/lessee of the
forest -- can claim an innate kinship to a tree. This is not to be an apologist
for clear-cutting, but rather to say that the merits of cutting vs. preserving
trees cannot be decided according to which persons or groups have the
"truest" relationship to nature.
The crucial point is
that all three groups have an interactive relationship with nature: the
differences lie in their conflicting conceptions of nature,
their conflicting uses of nature, and how they incorporate
nature into their systems of values (be they community, economic or spiritual
values). This clash of human values reveals how much the ostensibly separate
domains of community development and environmental protection overlap, and
suggests that planners should do better in combining social and environmental
models. One sees this clash of values in many environmental battles: between
the interests of urban residents and those of subsidized irrigation farmers in
California water politics; between beach homeowners and coastal managers trying
to control erosion; between rich and poor neighborhoods, in the siting of
incinerators; between farmers and environmentalists, in restrictions by open
space zoning. Even then-President George Bush weighed into such disputes during
his 1992 campaign when he commented to a group of loggers that finally people
should be valued more than spotted owls (his own take on the interspecies
equity issue). Inequity and the imbalance of political power are often issues
at the heart of economic-environmental conflicts.
Recognition that the
terrain of nature is contested need not, however, cast us adrift on a sea of
socially-constructed relativism where "nature" appears as an
arbitrary idea of no substance (Bird 1987; Soja 1989). Rather, we are made to
rethink the idea and to see the appreciation of nature as an historically
evolved sensibility. I suspect that radical environmentalists would criticize
this perspective as anthropocentric environmentalism, and argue instead for an
ecocentric world view that puts the Earth first (Sessions 1992; Parton 1993).
It is true that an anthropocentric view, if distorted, can lead to an arrogant
optimism about civilization's ability to reprogram nature through technologies
ranging from huge hydroelectric and nuclear plants down to genetic engineering.
A rigid belief in the anthropocentric labor theory of value, Marxist or
otherwise, can produce a modern-day Narcissus as a social-constructionist who
sees nature as merely reflecting the beauty of the human aesthetic, and the
value of human labor. In this light, a tree is devoid of value until it either
becomes part of a scenic area or is transformed into lumber. On the other hand,
even as radical, ecocentric environmentalists claim to see "true
nature" beyond the city limits, they are blind to how their own world view
and their definition of nature itself are shaped by their socialization. The
choice between an anthropocentric or an ecocentric world view is a false one.
We are all unavoidably anthropocentric; the question is which anthropomorphic
values and priorities we will apply to the natural and the social world around
us.
Sustainable
Development: Reaching the Elusive Center of the Triangle
If the
three corners of the triangle represent key goals in planning, and the three
axes represent the three resulting conflicts, then I will define the center of
the triangle as representing sustainable development: the balance of these
three goals. Getting to the center, however, will not be so easy. It is one
thing to locate sustainability in the abstract, but quite another to reorganize
society to get there.
At first glance, the widespread advocacy of sustainable
development is astonishing, given its revolutionary implications for daily life
(World Commission 1987; Daly and Cobb 1989; Rees 1989; World Bank, 1989;
Goodland 1990; Barrett and Bohlen 1991; Korten 1991; Van der Ryn and Calthorpe
1991). It is getting hard to refrain from sustainable development; arguments
against it are inevitably attached to the strawman image of a greedy, myopic
industrialist. Who would now dare to speak up in opposition? Two
interpretations of the bandwagon for sustainable development suggest
themselves. The pessimistic thought is that sustainable development has been
stripped of its transformative power and reduced to its lowest common
denominator. After all, if both the World Bank and radical ecologists now
believe in sustainability, the concept can have no teeth: it is so malleable as
to mean many things to many people without requiring commitment to any specific
policies. Actions speak louder than words, and though all endorse
sustainability, few will actually practice it. Furthermore, any concept fully
endorsed by all parties must surely be bypassing the heart of the conflict. Set
a goal far enough into the future, and even conflicting interests will seem to
converge along parallel lines. The concept certainly appears to violate the
Karl Popper's requirement that propositions be falsifiable, for to reject
sustainability is to embrace nonsustainability -- and who dares to sketch that
future? (Ironically, the nonsustainable scenario is the easiest to define:
merely the extrapolation of our current way of life.)
Yet there is also an optimistic interpretation of the broad
embrace given sustainability: the idea has become hegemonic, an accepted
meta-narrative, a given. It has shifted from being a variable to being the
parameter of the debate, almost certain to be integrated into any future
scenario of development. We should therefore neither be surprised that no
definition has been agreed upon, nor fear that this reveals a fundamental flaw
in the concept. In the battle of big public ideas, sustainability has won: the
task of the coming years is simply to work out the details, and to narrow the
gap between its theory and practice.
Is
Sustainable Development a Useful Concept?
Some
environmentalists argue that if sustainable development is necessary, it
therefore must be possible. Perhaps so, but if you are stranded at the bottom
of a deep well, a ladder may be impossible even though necessary. The answer
espoused may be as much an ideological as a scientific choice, depending on
whether ones loyalty is to Malthus or Daly. The more practical question is
whether sustainability is a useful concept for planners. The answer here is
mixed. The goal may be too far away and holistic to be operational: that is, it
may not easily break down into concrete, short-term steps. We also might be
able to define sustainability yet unable to ever actually
measure it or even know, one day in the future, that we had achieved it. An old
eastern proverb identifies the western confusion of believing that to name
something is to know it. That may be the danger in automatically embracing
sustainable development: a facile confidence that by adding the term "sustainable"
to all our existing planning documents and tools (sustainable zoning,
sustainable economic development, sustainable transportation planning), we
are doing sustainable planning. Conversely, one can do much
beneficial environmental work without ever requiring attention to the concept
of sustainability.
Yet sustainability can be a helpful concept in that it posits the
long-term planning goal of a social-environmental system in balance. It is a
unifying concept, enormously appealing to the imagination, that brings together
many different environmental concerns under one overarching value. It defines a
set of social priorities and articulates how society values the economy, the
environment, and equity (Paehlke 1994, 360). In theory, it allows us not only to
calculate whether we have attained sustainability, but also to determine how
far away we are (actual measurement, though, is another, harder task). Clearly
it can be argued that, though initially flawed and vague, the concept can be
transformed and refined to be of use to planners.
History,
Equity and Sustainable Development
One
obstacle to an accurate, working definition of sustainability may well be the
historical perspective that sees the practice as pre-existing, either in our
past or as a Platonic concept. I believe instead that our sustainable future
does not yet exist, either in reality or even in strategy. We do not yet know
what it will look like; it is being socially constructed through a sustained
period of conflict negotiation and resolution. This is a process of innovation,
not of discovery and converting the nonbelievers.
This point brings us to the practice of looking for sustainable
development in preindustrial and nonwestern cultures (a common though not
universal practice). Searching for our future in our indigenous past is
instructive at both the philosophical and the practical level (Turner 1983;
Duerr 1985). Yet it is also problematical, tapping into a myth that our
salvation lies in the preindustrial sustainable culture. The international
division of labor and trade, the movement of most people away from agriculture
into cities, and exponential population growth lead us irrevocably down a
unidirectional, not a circular path: the transformation of preindustrial,
indigenous settlements into mass urban society is irreversible. Our modern path
to sustainability lies forward, not behind us.
The key difference between those indigenous, sustainable
communities and ours is that they had no choice but to be sustainable. Bluntly
stated, if they cut down too many trees or ruined the soil, they would die out.
Modern society has the options presented by trade, long-term storage, and
synthetic replacements; if we clear-cut a field, we have subsequent options
that our ancestors didn't. In this situation, we must voluntarily
choose sustainable practices, since there is no immediate survival or
market imperative to do so. Although the long-term effects of a nonsustainable
economy are certainly dangerous, the feedback mechanisms are too long-term to prod
us in the right direction.
Why do we often romanticize the sustainable past? Some are
attracted to the powerful spiritual link between humans and nature that has
since been lost. Such romanticists tend however, to overlook the more harsh and
unforgiving aspects of being so dependent on the land. Two hundred years ago,
Friedrich Schiller (1965, 28) noted the tendency of utopian thinkers to take
their dream for the future and posit it as their past, thus giving it
legitimacy as a cyclical return to the past. This habit is not unique to
ecotopians (Kumar 1991); some religious fundamentalists also justify their
utopian urgency by drawing on the myth of a paradise lost. Though Marxists
don't glorify the past in the same way, they, too, manage to anticipate a static system
of balance and harmony that nonetheless will require a cataclysmic,
revolutionary social transformation to reach. All three ideologies posit some
basic flaw in society -- be it western materialism, original sin, or capitalism
-- whose identification and cure will free us from conflict. Each ideology sees
a fundamental alienation as the danger to overcome: alienation from nature,
from god, or from work. Each group is so critical of existing society that it
would seem a wonder we have made it this far; but this persistence of human
society despite the dire prognoses of utopians tells us something.
What is the fall-out from such historical thinking? By neglecting
the powerful momentum of modern industrial and postindustrial society, it both
points us in the wrong direction and makes it easier to marginalize the
proponents of sustainable development. It also carries an anti-urban sentiment
that tends to neglect both the centrality and the plight of megacities. Modern
humans are unique among species in their propensity to deal with nature's
threats, not only through flight and burrowing and biological adaptation, nor
simply through spiritual understanding, but also through massive population
growth, complex social division of labor, and the fundamental, external
transformation of their once-natural environment (the building of cities).
Certainly the fixation on growth, industry, and competition has degraded the
environment. Yet one cannot undo urban-industrial society. Rather, one must
continue to innovate through to the other side of industrialization, to reach a
more sustainable economy.
The cyclical historical view of some environmentalists also
hinders a critical understanding of equity, since that view attributes to the
environment a natural state of equality rudely upset by modern society. Yet
nature is inherently neither equal nor unequal, and at times can be downright
brutal. The human observer projects a sense of social equity onto nature,
through a confusion, noted by Schiller, of the idealized future with myths
about our natural past. To gain a sense of historical legitimacy, we project
our socially constructed sense of equality onto the past, creating revisionist
history in which nature is fair and compassionate. Society's path to equality is
perceived not as an uncertain progress from barbarism to justice, but rather as
a return to an original state of harmony as laid out in nature. In this
thinking, belief in an ecological balance and a social balance, entwined in the
pre-industrial world, conjures up an eco-Garden of Eden "lost" by
modern society.
It will be more useful to let go of this mythic belief in our
involuntary diaspora from a pre-industrial, ecotopian Eden. The conflation of
ecological diasporas and utopias constrains our search for creative, urban
solutions to social-environmental conflict. By relinquishing it, we will
understand that notions of equity were not lying patiently in wait in nature,
to be first discovered by indigenous peoples, then lost by colonialists, and
finally rediscovered by modern society in the late twentieth century. This is
certainly not to say that nature can teach us nothing. The laws of nature are
not the same thing, however, as natural law, nor does ecological equilibrium
necessarily generate normative principles of equity. Though we turn to nature
to understand the context, dynamics, and effects of the economic-environmental
conflict, we must turn to social norms to decide what balance is fair and just.
How, then, do we define what is fair? I propose viewing social
justice as the striving towards a more equal distribution of resources among
social groups across the space of cities and of nations -- a definition of
"fair" distribution. It should be noted that societies view
themselves "fair" if the procedures of allocation
treat people equally, even if the substantive outcome is
unbalanced. (One would hope that equal treatment is but the first step towards
narrowing material inequality.) The environmental movement expands the space
for this "equity" in two ways: (1) intergenerationally (present
versus future generations) and (2) across species (as in animal rights, deep
ecology, and legal "standing" for trees). The two added dimensions of
equity remain essentially abstractions, however, since no one from the future
or from other species can speak up for their "fair share" of
resources. Selfless advocates (or selfish ventriloquists) "speak for
them."
This expansion of socio-spatial "equity" to include
future generations and other species not only makes the concept more complex;
it also creates the possibility for contradictions among the different calls
for "fairness." Slowing worldwide industrial expansion may preserve
more of the world's resources for the future (thereby increasing
intergenerational equity), but it may also undermine the efforts of the
underdeveloped world to approach the living standards of the west (thereby
lowering international equity). Battles over Native American fishing practices,
the spotted owl, and restrictive farmland preservation each thrust together
several divergent notions of "fairness." It is through resolving the
three sorts of conflicts on the planner's triangle that society iteratively
forms its definition of what is fair.
The Path
Towards Sustainable Development
There are
two final aspects of the fuzzy definition of sustainability: its path and its
outcome. The basic premise of sustainable development is one that, like the
long-term goal of a balanced U.S. budget, is hard not to like. As with
eliminating the national debt, however, two troubling questions about
sustainable development remain: How are you going to get there? Once you get
there, what are the negative consequences? Planners don't yet have adequate
answers to these two questions, that is, as yet they have no concrete
strategies to achieve sustainable development, nor do they know how to counter
the political resistance to it.
On the path towards a sustainable future, the
steps are often too vague, as with sweeping calls for a "spiritual
transformation" as the prerequisite for environmental transformation.
Sometimes the call for sustainable development seems to serve as a vehicle for
sermonizing about the moral and spiritual corruption of the industrial world
(undeniable). Who would not want to believe in a holistic blending of economic
and ecological values in each of our planners, who would then go out into the
world and, on each project, internally and seamlessly merge the interests of
jobs and nature, as well as of social justice? That is, the call to planners
would be to stand at every moment at the center of the triangle.
But this aim is too reminiscent of our naive belief during the
1950s and 1960s in comprehensive planning for a single "public
interest," before the incrementalists and advocacy planners pulled the rug
out from under us (Lindblom 1959; Altshuler 1965; Davidoff 1965; Fainstein and
Fainstein 1971). I suspect that planners' criticisms of the sustainable
development movement in the coming years will parallel the critique of
comprehensive planning 30 years ago: The incrementalists will argue that one
cannot achieve a sustainable society in a single grand leap, for it requires
too much social and ecological information and is too risky. The advocacy
planners will argue that no common social interest in sustainable development
exists, and that bureaucratic planners will invariably create a sustainable
development scheme that neglects the interests both of the poor and of nature.
To both groups of critics, the prospect of integrating economic, environmental
and equity interests will seem forced and artificial. States will require
communities to prepare "Sustainable Development Master Plans," which
will prove to be glib wish lists of goals and suspiciously vague implementation
steps. To achieve consensus for the plan, language will be reduced to the
lowest common denominator, and the pleasing plans will gather dust.
An alternative is to let holistic sustainable development be a
long-range goal; it is a worthy one, for planners do need a vision of a more sustainable
urban society. But during the coming years, planners will confront deep-seated
conflicts among economic, social and environmental interests that cannot be
wished away through admittedly appealing images of a community in harmony with
nature. One is no more likely to abolish the economic-environmental conflict
completely by achieving sustainable bliss than one is to eliminate completely
the boundaries between the city and the wilderness, between the public and
private spheres, between the haves and have-nots. Nevertheless, one can diffuse
the conflict, and find ways to avert its more destructive fall-out.
My concern about the ramifications of a
sustainable future is one that is often expressed: steady-state, no-growth
economics would be likely to relegate much of the developing world -- and the
poor within the industrialized world -- to a state of persistent poverty. The
advocates of sustainable development rightly reject as flawed the premise of
conventional economics that only a growth economy can achieve social
redistribution. And growth economics has, indeed, also exacerbated the
environment's degradation. However, it is wishful thinking to assume that a
sustainable economy will automatically ensure a socially just distribution of
resources. The vision of no-growth (commonly though not universally assumed to
characterize sustainable development) raises powerful fears, and planners
should be savvy to such fears. Otherwise, they will understand neither the
potential dangers of steady-state economics nor the nature of the opposition to
sustainable development.
Rethinking/Redefining
Sustainable Development
Despite
the shortcomings in the current formulation of sustainable development, the
concept retains integrity and enormous potential. It simply needs to be
redefined and made more precise. First, one should avoid a dichotomous,
black-and-white view of sustainability. We should think of American society not
as a corrupt, wholly unsustainable one that has to be made pure and wholly
sustainable, but rather as a hybrid of both sorts of practices. Our purpose,
then, should be to move further towards sustainable practices in an
evolutionary progression.
Second, we should broaden the idea of "sustainability."
If "crisis" is defined as the inability of a system to reproduce
itself, then sustainability is the opposite: the long-term ability of a system
to reproduce. This criterion applies not only to natural ecosystems, but to
economic and political systems as well. By this definition, western society already
does much to sustain itself: economic policy and corporate strategies (e.g.,
investment, training, monetary policy) strive to reproduce the macro- and
micro-economies. Similarly, governments, parties, labor unions, and other
political agents strive to reproduce their institutions and interests.
Society's shortcoming is that as it strives to sustain its political and
economic systems, it often neglects to sustain the ecological system. The goal
for planning is therefore a broader agenda: to sustain, simultaneously and in
balance, these three sometimes competing, sometimes complementary systems.
Third, it will be helpful to distinguish initially between two
levels of sustainability: specific versus general (or local versus global). One
might fairly easily imagine and achieve sustainability in a single sector
and/or locality, for example, converting a Pacific Northwest community to
sustained-yield timber practices. Recycling, solar power, cogeneration, and
conservation can lower consumption of nonsustainable resources. To achieve
complete sustainability across all sectors and/or all places, however, requires
such complex restructuring and redistribution that the only feasible path to
global sustainability is likely to be a long, incremental accumulation of local
and industry-specific advances.
What this incremental, iterative approach means is that planners
will find their vision of a sustainable city developed best at the conclusion
of contested negotiations over land use, transportation, housing, and economic
development policies, not as the premise for beginning the effort. To first
spend years in the hermetic isolation of universities and environmental groups,
perfecting the theory of sustainable development, before testing it in
community development is backwards. That approach sees sustainable development
as an ideal society outside the conflicts of the planner's triangle, or as the
tranquil "eye of the hurricane" at the triangle's center. As with the
ideal comprehensive plan, it is presumed that the objective, technocratic
merits of a perfected sustainable development scheme will ensure society's
acceptance. But one cannot reach the sustainable center of the planner's
triangle in a single, holistic leap to a pre-ordained balance.
The Task
Ahead for Planners: Seeking Sustainable Development within the Triangle of
Planning Conflicts
The role
of planners is therefore to engage the current challenge of sustainable
development with a dual, interactive strategy: (1) to manage and resolve
conflict; and (2) to promote creative technical, architectural, and
institutional solutions. Planners must both negotiate the procedures of the
conflict and promote a substantive vision of sustainable development.
Procedural
Paths to Sustainable Development: Conflict Negotiation
In
negotiation and conflict resolution (Bingham 1986; Susskind and Cruikshank
1987; Crowfoot and Wondolleck 1990), rather than pricing externalities, common
ground is established at the negotiation table, where the conflicting economic,
social, and environmental interests can be brought together. The potential
rewards are numerous: not only an outcome that balances all parties, but
avoidance of heavy legal costs and long-lasting animosity. Negotiated conflict
resolution can also lead to a better understanding of one's opponent's
interests and values, and even of one's own interests. The very process of
lengthy negotiation can be a powerful tool to mobilize community involvement
around social and environmental issues. The greatest promise, of course, is a
win-win outcome: finding innovative solutions that would not have come out of
traditional, adversarial confrontation. Through skillfully led back-and-forth
discussion, the parties can separate their initial, clashing substantive
demands from their underlying interests, which may be more compatible. For
example, environmentalists and the timber industry could solve their initial
dispute over building a logging road, through alternative road design and other
mitigation measures (Crowfoot and Wondolleck 1990, 32-52).
However, conflict resolution is no panacea. Sometimes conflicting
demands express fundamental conflicts of interest. The either-or nature of the
technology or ecology may preclude a win-win outcome, as in an all-or-nothing
dispute over a proposed hydroelectric project (Reisner 1987) -- you either
build it or you don't. An overwhelming imbalance of power between the opposing
groups also can thwart resolution (Crowfoot and Wondolleck 1990, 4). A powerful
party can simply refuse to participate. It is also hard to negotiate a
comprehensive resolution for a large number of parties.
Planners are likely to have the best success in using conflict
resolution when there is a specific, concise dispute (rather than an amorphous
ideological clash); all interested parties agree to participate (and don't
bypass the process through the courts); each party feels on equal ground; there
are a variety of possible compromises and innovative solutions; both parties
prefer a solution to an impasse; and a skilled third-party negotiator
facilitates. The best resolution strategies seem to include two areas of
compromise and balance: the procedural (each party is represented and willing
to compromise); and the substantive (the solution is a compromise, such as
multiple land uses or a reduced development density).
Procedural
Paths to Sustainable Development: Redefining the Language of the Conflict
A second
strategy is to bridge the chasms between the languages of economics,
environmentalism, and social justice. Linguistic differences, which reflect
separate value hierarchies, are a major obstacle to common solutions. All too
often, the economists speak of incentives and marginal rates, the ecologists
speak of carrying capacity and biodiversity, the advocate planners speak of
housing rights, empowerment, and discrimination, and each side accuses the
others of being "out of touch" (Campbell 1992).
The planner therefore needs to act as a translator, assisting each
group to understand the priorities and reasoning of the others. Economic,
ecological and social thought may at a certain level be incommensurable, yet a
level may still be found where all three may be brought together. To offer an
analogy, a Kenyan Gikuyu text cannot be fully converted into English without
losing something in translation; a good translation, nevertheless, is the best
possible way to bridge two systems of expression that will never be one, and it
is preferable to incomprehension.
The danger of translation is that one language will dominate the
debate and thus define the terms of the solution. It is essential to exert
equal effort to translate in each direction, to prevent one linguistic culture
from dominating the other (as English has done in neo-colonial Africa). Another
lesson from the neocolonial linguistic experience is that it is crucial for
each social group to express itself in its own language before any translation.
The challenge for planners is to write the best translations among the
languages of the economic, the ecological, and the social views, and to avoid a
quasi-colonial dominance by the economic lingua franca, by creating
equal two-way translations.
For example, planners need better tools to understand their cities
and regions not just as economic systems, or static inventories of natural
resources, but also as environmental systems that are part of
regional and global networks trading goods, information, resources and
pollution. At the conceptual level, translating the economic vocabulary of
global cities, the spatial division of labor, regional restructuring, and
technoburbs/edge cities into environmental language would be a worthy start; at
the same time, of course, the vocabulary of biodiversity, landscape linkages,
and carrying capacity should be translated to be understandable by economic
interests.
This bilingual translation should extend to the empirical level. I
envision extending the concept of the "trade balance" to include an
"environmental balance," which covers not just commodities, but also
natural resources and pollution. Planners should improve their data collection
and integration to support the environmental trade balance. They should apply
economic-ecological bilingualism not only to the content of data, but also to
the spatial framework of the data, by rethinking the geographic boundaries of
planning and analysis. Bioregionalists advocate having the spatial scale for
planning reflect the scale of natural phenomena (e.g., the
extent of a river basin, vegetation zones, or the dispersion range of
metropolitan air pollution); economic planners call for a spatial scale to
match the social phenomena (e.g., highway networks, municipal
boundaries, labor market areas, new industrial districts). The solution is to
integrate these two scales and overlay the economic and ecological geographies
of planning. The current merging of environmental Raster (grid-based) and
infrastructural vector-based data in Geographic Information Systems (GIS)
recognizes the need for multiple layers of planning boundaries (Wiggins 1993).
Translation can thus be a powerful planner's skill, and
interdisciplinary planning education already provides some multilingualism.
Moreover, the idea of sustainability lends itself nicely to the meeting on
common ground of competing value systems. Yet translation has its limits.
Linguistic differences often represent real, intractable differences in values.
An environmental dispute may arise not from a misunderstanding alone; both
sides may clearly understand that their vested interests fundamentally clash,
no matter how expressed. At this point, translation must give way to other
strategies. The difficulties are exacerbated when one party has greater power,
and so shapes the language of the debate as well as prevailing in its outcome.
In short, translation, like conflict negotiation, reveals both the promises and
the limitations of communication-based conflict resolution.
Other
Procedural Paths
Two
other, more traditional approaches deserve mention. One is political pluralism:
let the political arena decide conflicts, either directly (e.g., a referendum
on an open space bond act, or a California state proposition on nuclear power),
or indirectly (e.g., elections decided on the basis of candidates'
environmental records and promised legislation). The key elements here,
political debate and ultimately the vote, allow much wider participation in the
decision than negotiation does. However, a binary vote cannot as easily handle
complex issues, address specific land-use conflicts, or develop subtle,
creative solutions. Choosing the general political process as a strategy for
deciding conflict also takes the process largely out of the hands of planners.
The other traditional strategy is to develop market mechanisms to
link economic and environmental priorities. Prices are made the commonality
that bridges the gap between the otherwise noncommensurables of trees and
timber, open space and real estate. The market place is chosen as the arena
where society balances its competing values. This economistic approach to the
environment reduces pollution to what the economist Edwin Mills (1978, 15)
called "a problem in resource allocation." This approach can decide
conflicts along the economic-environmental axis (the resource conflict), but
often neglects equity. However, the market does seem to be dealing better with
environmental externalities than it did ten or twenty years ago. Internalizing
externalities, at the least, raises the issues of social justice and equity:
e.g., who will pay for cleaning up abandoned industrial sites or compensate for
the loss of fishing revenues due to oil spills. The recent establishment of a
pollution credit market in the South Coast Air Quality Management District, for
example, is a step in the right direction -- despite criticism that the
pollution credits were initially given away for free (Robinson, 1993).
The role of the planner in all four of these approaches is to
arrange the procedures for making decisions, not to set the substance of the
actual outcomes. In some cases, the overall structure for decision-making
already exists (the market and the political system). In other cases, however,
the planner must help shape that structure (a mediation forum; a common
language), which, done successfully, gives the process credibility. The actual
environmental outcomes nevertheless remain unknowable: you don't know in
advance if the environment will actually be improved. For example,
environmentalists and developers heralded the Coachella Valley Fringe-Toed
Lizard Habitat Conservation Plan as a model process to balance the interests of
development and conservation; yet the actual outcome may not adequately protect
the endangered lizard (Beatley 1992, 15-16). Similarly, although the New Jersey
State Development Plan was praised for its innovative cross-acceptance
procedure, the plan itself arguably has not altered the state's urban sprawl.
The final issue that arises is whether the planner should play the
role of neutral moderator, or of advocate representing a single party; this has
been a long-standing debate in the field. Each strategy has its virtues.
Substantive
Paths to Sustainable Development: Land Use and Design
Planners
have substantive knowledge of how cities, economies, and ecologies interact,
and they should put forth specific, farsighted designs that promote the
sustainable city. The first area is traditional planning tools of land-use
design and control. The potential for balance between economic and
environmental interests exists in design itself, as in a greenbelt community
(Elson 1986). Sometimes the land-use solution is simply to divide a contested
parcel into two parcels: a developed and a preserved. This solution can take
crude forms at times, such as the "no-net-loss" policy that endorses
the dubious practice of creating wetlands. A different example, Howard's
turn-of-the century Garden City (1965), can be seen as a territorially symbolic
design for balance between the economy and the environment, though its explicit
language was that of town-country balance. It is a design's articulated balance
between the built development and the unbuilt wilderness that promises the
economic-environmental balance. Designs for clustered developments, higher
densities, and live-work communities move toward such a balance (Rickaby 1987;
Commission of the European Communities 1990; Hudson 1991; Van der Rys and
Calthorpe 1991). Some dispute the inherent benefits of the compact city
(Breheny 1992). A further complication is that not all economic-environmental
conflicts have their roots in spatial or architectural problems. As a result,
ostensible solutions may be merely symbols of ecological-economic balance,
without actually solving the conflict.
Nevertheless, land-use planning arguably remains the most powerful
tool available to planners, who should not worry too much if it does not manage
all problems. The trick in resolving environmental conflicts through land-use
planning is to reconcile the conflicting territorial logics of human and of
natural habitats. Standard real estate development reduces open space to
fragmented, static, green islands -- exactly what the landscape ecologists
deplore as unable to preserve biodiversity. Wildlife roam and migrate, and
require large expanses of connected landscape (Hudson 1991). So both the
ecological and the economic systems require the interconnectivity of a critical
mass of land to be sustainable. Though we live in a three-dimensional world,
land is a limited resource with essentially two dimensions (always excepting
air and burrowing/mining spaces). The requirement of land's spatial
interconnectivity is thus hard to achieve for both systems in one region: the
continuity of one system invariably fragments continuity of the other. So the
guiding challenge for land-use planning is to achieve simultaneously spatial/territorial
integrity for both systems. Furthermore, a sustainable development that aspires
to social justice must also find ways to avoid the land-use manifestations of
uneven development: housing segregation, unequal property-tax funding of public
schools, jobs-housing imbalance, the spatial imbalance of economic opportunity,
and unequal access to open space and recreation.
Substantive
Paths to Sustainable Development: Bioregionalism
A
comprehensive vision of sustainable land use is bioregionalism, both in its
1920s articulation by the Regional Planning Association of America (Sussman
1976) and its contemporary variation (Sale 1985; Andrus et al. 1990; Campbell
1992). The movement's essential belief is that rescaling communities and the
economy according to the ecological boundaries of a physical region will
encourage sustainability. The regional scale presumably stimulates greater
environmental awareness: it is believed that residents of small-scale,
self-sufficient regions will be aware of the causes and effects of their
environmental actions, thereby reducing externalities. Regions will live within
their means, and bypass the environmental problems caused by international
trade and exporting pollution.
The bioregional vision certainly has its shortcomings, including
the same fuzzy, utopian thinking found in other writing about sustainable
development. Its ecological determinism also puts too much faith in the
regional "spatial fix": no geographic scale can, in itself, eliminate
all conflict, for not all conflict is geographic. Finally, the call for
regional self-reliance -- a common feature of sustainable development concepts
(Korten 1991, 184) -- might relegate the regional economy to underdevelopment
in an otherwise nationally and internationally interdependent world. Yet it can
be effective to visualize sustainable regions within an interdependent world
full of trade, migration, information flows and capital flows, and to know the
difference between healthy interdependence and parasitic
dependence, that is, dependence on other regions' resources that is
equivalent to depletion. Interdependence does not always imply an imbalance of
power, nor does self-sufficiency guarantee equality. Finally, the bioregional
perspective can provide a foundation for understanding conflicts among a
region's interconnected economic, social and ecological networks.
Other
Substantive Paths
One other
approach is technological improvement, such as alternative fuels, conservation
mechanisms, recycling, alternative materials, and new mass transit design.
Stimulated by competition, regulation or government subsidies, such advances
reduce the consumption of natural resources per unit of production and thereby
promise to ameliorate conflict over their competing uses, creating a win-win
solution. However, this method is not guaranteed to serve those purposes, for
gains in conservation are often cancelled out by rising demand for the final
products. The overall increase in demand for gasoline despite improvements in
automobile fuel efficiency is one example of how market forces can undermine
technologically-achieved environmental improvements. Nor, importantly, do
technological improvements guarantee fairer distribution.
The role of the planner in all these substantive strategies (land
use, bioregionalism, technological improvement) is to design outcomes, with
less emphasis on the means of achieving them. The environmental ramifications
of the solutions are known or at least estimated, but the political means to
achieve legitimacy are not. There also is a trade-off between comprehensiveness
(bioregions) and short-term achievability (individual technological
improvements).
Merging
the Substantive and Procedural
The
individual shortcomings of the approaches described above suggest that
combining them can achieve both political and substantive progress in the
environmental-economic crisis. The most successful solutions seem to undertake
several different resolution strategies at once. For example, negotiation among
developers, city planners, and land-use preservationists can produce an
innovative, clustered design for a housing development, plus a per-unit fee for
preserving open space. Substantive vision combined with negotiating skills thus
allows planners to create win-win solutions, rather than either negotiating in
a zero-sum game or preparing inert, ecotopian plans. This approach is not a
distant ideal for planners: they already have, from their education and
experience, both this substantive knowledge and this political savvy.
In the end, however, the planner must also deal with conflicts
where one or more parties have no interest in resolution. One nonresolution
tactic is the NIMBY, Not In My Back Yard, response: a crude marriage of local
initiative and the age-old externalizing of pollution. This "take it
elsewhere" strategy makes no overall claim to resolve conflict, though it
can be a productive form of resistance rather than just irrational parochialism
(Lake 1993). Nor does eco-terrorism consider balance. Instead, it replaces the
defensive stance of NIMBY with offensive, confrontational, symbolic action.
Resolution is also avoided out of cavalier confidence that one's own side can
manage the opposition through victory, not compromise ("My side will win,
so why compromise?"). Finally, an "I don't care" stance avoids
the conflict altogether. Unfortunately, this ostensible escapism often masks a
more pernicious NIMBY or "my side will win" hostility, just below the
surface.
Planners: Leaders or Followers in Resolving Economic-Environmental Conflicts?
I turn
finally to the question of whether planners are likely to be leaders or
followers in resolving economic-environmental conflicts. One would think that
it would be natural for planners, being interdisciplinary and familiar with the
three goals of balancing social equity, jobs, and environmental protection, to
take the lead in resolving such conflicts. Of the conflict resolution scenarios
mentioned above, those most open to planners' contributions involve the built
environment and local resources: land use, soil conservation, design issues,
recycling, solid waste, water treatment. Even solutions using the other
approaches -- environmental economic incentives, political compromise, and
environmental technology innovations -- that are normally undertaken at the
state and federal levels could also involve planners if moved to the local or
regional level.
But the planners' position at the forefront of change is not
assured, especially if the lead is taken up by other professions or at the
federal, not the local, level. The lively debate on whether gasoline
consumption can best be reduced through higher-density land uses (Newman and
Kenworthy 1989) or through energy taxes (Gordon and Richardson 1990) not only
reflected an ideological battle over interpreting research results and the
merits of planning intervention, but also demonstrated how local planning can
be made either central or marginal to resolving environmental-economic
conflicts. To hold a central place in the debate about sustainable development,
planners must exploit those areas of conflict where they have the greatest
leverage and expertise.
Certainly planners already have experience with both the dispute
over economic growth versus equity and that over economic growth versus
environmental protection. Yet it is the development conflict is where the real
action for planners will be: seeking to resolve both environmental and economic
equity issues at once. Here is where the profession can best make its unique
contribution. An obvious start would be for community development planners and
environmental planners to collaborate more (an alliance that an internal
Environmental Protection Agency memo found explosive enough for the agency to
consider defusing it) (Higgins 1994). One possible joint task is to expand
current public-private partnership efforts to improve environmental health in
the inner city. This urban-based effort would help planners bypass the danger
of environmental elitism that besets many suburban, white-oriented environmental
organizations.
If planners move in this direction, they will join the growing
environmental justice movement, which emerged in the early 1980s and combined
minority community organizing with environmental concerns (Higgins 1994). The
movement tries to reduce environmental hazards that directly affect poor
residents, who are the least able to fight pollution, be it the direct result
of discriminatory siting decisions or the indirect result of housing and
employment discrimination. The poor, being the least able to move away, are
especially tied to place and therefore to the assistance or neglect of local
planners. Understandably, local civil rights leaders have been preoccupied for
so long with seeking economic opportunity and social justice that they have
paid less attention to inequities in the local environment. The challenge for
poor communities is now to expand their work on the property conflict to
address the development conflict as well, that is, to challenge the false
choice of jobs over the environment. An urban vision of sustainable
development, infused with a belief in social and environmental justice, can
guide these efforts.
Yet even with the rising acceptance of sustainable development,
planners will not always be able, on their own, to represent and balance
social, economic and environmental interests simultaneously. The professional
allegiances, skills, and bureaucracies of the profession are too constraining
to allow that. Pretending at all times to be at the center of the planner's
triangle will only make sustainability a hollow term. Instead, the trick will
be for individual planners to identify their specific loyalties and roles in
these conflicts accurately: that is, to orient themselves in the triangle.
Planners will have to decide whether they want to remain outside the conflict
and act as mediators, or jump into the fray and promote their own visions of
ecological-economic development, sustainable or otherwise. Both planning
behaviors are needed.
Source: Scott Campbell , Urban and Regional Planning Program, Urban Planning and the Contradictions of Sustainable Development retrieved at http://www-personal.umich.edu/~sdcamp/Ecoeco/Greencities.html
Source: Scott Campbell , Urban and Regional Planning Program, Urban Planning and the Contradictions of Sustainable Development retrieved at http://www-personal.umich.edu/~sdcamp/Ecoeco/Greencities.html